Publication:
A Theory of Vintage Capital Investment and Energy Use

Loading...
Thumbnail Image
Official URL
Full text at PDC
Publication Date
2013-10
Advisors (or tutors)
Editors
Journal Title
Journal ISSN
Volume Title
Publisher
Citations
Google Scholar
Research Projects
Organizational Units
Journal Issue
Abstract
In this paper we propose a theory of investment and energy use to study the response of macroeconomic aggregates to energy price shocks. In our theory this response depends on the interaction between the energy efficiency built in capital goods (which is irreversible throughout their lifetime) and the growth rate of Investment Specific Technological Change (ISTC hereafter). ISTC reduces the cost to produce investment goods and renders them more productive. Depending on which effect is stronger, higher ISTC is a complement or a substitute for energy efficiency and, thus, affects differently aggregate energy demand. Our theory provides a discipline to identify both effects since it predicts that the relative price of investment goods (not quality adjusted as well as quality adjusted) depends not only on the two ISTC shocks but also on the energy efficiency built into capital units. Thus, we can disentangle the effects of ISTC shocks from the effects of energy efficiency: a distinction that the literature on ISTC growth abstracts from. Our theory can account for the fall of energy use per unit of output observed during the 1990s, a period in which energy prices fell below trend. By increasing investment in the years of high ISTC growth, the economy was increasing the average efficiency of the economy (the capital-energy ratio), shielding the economy against the impact of the 2003-08 price shock.
Description
JEL Classification: E22, E23. This paper was previously entitled “A Theory of Energy Use”. We thank Raouf Boucekkine for his comments to a first version of this paper. We also thank Fabrice Collard, Andrés Erosa, Cyril Monnet, Omar Licandro, Franck Portier and Jesús Ruiz for helpful comments, and Manuel García and Alberto Sánchez for excellent research assistance. Díaz, and Puch, thank respectively the Dirección General de Investigación, projects ECO2010-20614 and ECO2010-17943, for financial support, and the EUI for its support during part of this research. Puch also thanks Fundación FocusAbengoa and FEDEA. We are grateful to participants of conferences 2012 REDg, 2012 SED Meetings, 2011 Wien Macro Workshop, as well as workshop participants at EUI.
Unesco subjects
Keywords
Citation
Acemoglu, D. (2002). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 9(4), 781–809. Acemoglu, D., P. Aghion, L. Bursztyn, and D. Hemous (2012, February). The environment and directed technical change. American Economic Review 102(1), 131–66. 
Atkeson, A. and P. J. Kehoe (1999). Models of energy use: Putty-putty versus putty-clay. American Economic Review 89(4), 1028–43.
 Baumeister, C. and G. Peersman (2012). The role of time-varying price elasticities in accounting for volatility changes in the crude oil market. Journal of Applied Econometrics 27(4). Berndt, E. R. and D. O. Wood (1975). Technology, prices and the derived demand for energy. Review of Economics and Statistics 57(3), 259–68. Blanchard, O. J. and J. Galí (2007, January). The macroeconomic effects of oil price shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? In International Dimensions of Monetary Policy, NBER Chs, pp. 373–421. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Bureau of Economic Analysis (2003). Fixed assets and consumer durable goods in the United States, 1925-97. http://www.bea.gov. Cooley, T. F. and E. C. Prescott (1995). Economic growth and business cycles. In T. F. Coo- ley (Ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Chapter 1, pp. 1–38. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cummins, J. G. and G. L. Violante (2002). Investment-specific technical change in the us (1947- 2000): Measurement and macroeconomic consequences. Review of Economic Dynamics 5(2), 243–284. Díaz, A., L. A. Puch, and M.D. Guilló (2004). Costly capital reallocation and energy use. Review of Economic Dynamics 7(2), 494–518. Edelstein, P. and L. Kilian (2007). The response of business fixed investment to changes in energy prices: A test of some hypotheses about the transmission of energy price shocks. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 7(1), 35. Fisher, J. D. M. (2006, June). The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114(3), 413–451. Gordon, R. J. (1990). The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: National Bureau of Economic Research Monograph Series. Gordon, R. J. (1996). NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Volume 11, Chapter Can Technology Improvements Cause Productivity Slowdowns?: Comment, pp. 259–267. The University of Chicago Press. Gort, M., J. Greenwood, and P. Rupert (1999, January). Measuring the rate of technological progress in structures. Review of Economic Dynamics 2(1), 207–230. Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell (1997). Long-run implications of investment-specific technological change. American Economic Review 87(3), 342–62. Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell (2000, January). The role of investment-specific technological change in the business cycle. European Economic Review 44(1), 91–115. Griffin, J. M. and P. R. Gregory (1976). An intercountry translog model of energy substitution responses. American Economic Review 66(5), 845–57. Hamilton, J. D. (2008). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Chapter Oil and the Macroe- conomy. Houndsmills, U.K. and New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Hassler, J., P. Krusell, and C. Olovsson (2012, October). Energy-saving technical change. Working Paper 18456, National Bureau of Economic Research. Justiniano, A., G. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti (2011). Investment shocks and the relative price of investment. Review of Economic Dynamics 14(1), 101–121. Kilian, L. (2008, December). The economic effects of energy price shocks. Journal of Economic Literature 46(4), 871–909. Knittel, C. R. (2011). Automobiles on steroids: Product attribute trade-offs and technological progress in the automobile sector. American Economic Review 101(7), 3368–99. Metcalf, G. E. (2008). An empirical analysis of energy intensity and its determinants at the state level. The Energy Journal 29(3), 1–26. Newell, R. G., A. B. Jaffe, and R. N. Stavins (1999). The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving technological change. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(3), 941–975. Pindyck, R. S. (1979). Interfuel substitution and the industrial demand for energy: An interna- tional comparison. Review of Economics and Statistics 29(2), 173–89. Pindyck, R. S. and J. J. Rotemberg (1983). Dynamic factor demands and the effects of energy price shocks. American Economic Review 73(5), 1066–79. Popp, D. (2002). Induced innovation and energy prices. American Economic Review 92 (1), 160– 180. Rodríguez-López, J. and J. L. Torres (2012, February). Technological sources of productivity growth in germany, japan, and the united states. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (01), 133–150. Sato, K. (1976). The meaning and measurement of the real value added index. The Review of Economics and Statistics 58(4), 434–442. Solow, R. M. (1960). Mathematical Methods in Social Sciences, 1959: Proceedings of the First Stanford Symposium, Chapter Investment and technological progress, pp. 89–104. Stanford University Press. Steinbuks, J. and K. Neuhoff (2010). Operational and investment response to energy prices in the OECD manufacturing sector. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics 1015, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge.